This is
a book that will save you a lot of time. Instead of reading dry, boring
economics books, you can read Heilbroner’s summary of the best of the best,
telling you about the lives of the most important economists, their greatest
works, and their significance to the modern-day study of economics. It’s
written very well, and I found it easy to read. He likes to describe the
economists’ theories and discoveries in the context of their lives and has great
details about who these men were. The book covers Adam Smith, Thomas Malthus, David
Ricardo, “the utopian socialists,” Karl Marx, the “Victorian economists,” Thorstein
Veblen, John Maynard Keynes, and Joseph Schumpeter.
Heilbroner
begins by telling us about the world before modern economics. For example, “there
was no such thing as land in the sense of freely salable, rent-producing
property.” He writes that since all land was under the feudal system, estates,
manors, and principalities owned by dukes, barons and such, people did not
freely sell land. These vassals saw their land as their birthright and never
sold it, rather going to war to get more. To sell it would be like the governor
of Massachusetts selling land to New Hampshire. Capitalism didn’t yet exist.
While people certainly bought and sold things, it wasn’t done freely. It was
all controlled from the top. For example, in 16th century England they
banned “workshops” that had hundreds of looms at the complaint of the guilds.
Innovations were squashed. In France in 1666 they ruled that any new
innovations in cloth weaving had to be approved by the oldest merchants and
weavers of the guild, guaranteeing failure almost always.
The
first economist discussed is Adam Smith, who did not “invent” capitalism, but described
the processes of the (capitalistic) British economy that had emerged by the
late 18th century. One of his greatest insights was seeing that not
nature, but labor was the source of value. Gold is not the source of value,
getting it out of the ground and shaping it is. Smith saw the division of labor
into specializations as a process that would only have positive economic
effects for 200 years, meaning it should already be over. Perhaps it is ending
as western economies slow down. He advocated for the government to protect
society against the value of others, administer courts of justice, and maintain
public works that no individual or small number of individuals would find profitable
to maintain. Other than those things, he felt that government should just get
out of the way and avoid messing up the economy.
The book
then turns to a friendly rivalry among two British economists, Thomas Malthus and
David Ricardo. While they were always friends, they argued about anything. For
example, Malthus identified that it can be possible for producers to produce too
much of a good, causing a “glut,” which Ricardo and most of the mainstream thought
was ridiculous. Today, we call that “glut” a recession and it certainly happens.
Ricardo is responsible for turning economics into a science by making it abstract,
taking what Adam Smith had written about English economy and making it
universal, discovering rules that underlay it. Malthus is famous today for
identifying the problem of increasing population, which, until he put it
forward, had always been considered to be a very good thing. The book then goes
into talking about the utopian socialists, who weren’t that interesting to me
except as a prelude to the real socialists, like Karl Marx.
Marx was
the best critic of the failures of the industrial revolution, which lay in what
he considered an excess of capitalism. Capitalists, essentially businessmen
with access to capital, A.K.A. lots of money, used their control of the job
market to pay people little and give them bad conditions. Who could blame him?
He lived in a brutal time full of worker abuses, child labor, and lots of death
and maiming on the job where you might work 70 hours a week. Due to historical
forces, people lost the land they lived on and moved to cities, where the only
thing they had to sell was their labor. He predicted that these intense social
conditions would cause the end of capitalism, and in some places, like the Soviet
Union, it did. However, in others, like Europe and the United States, we
responded with reforms to help workers while maintaining the benefits of capitalism.
Heilbroner
moves on to discuss several Victorian-era economists. These eonomists tended to
be much more optimistic about economic systems contemporarily in place. I found
it to be a less interesting chapter. However, I was interested in how he talked
about the expansion of imperialism, which was seen as a way to help domestic
markets. To keep their workers employed in workshops, imperializing countries needed
to produce lots of goods. However, they couldn’t sell them to themselves
forever because you only need so many of these things. As a result, it was
better to sell them to developing countries cheaply, offloading goods for
profits there while simultaneously making them dependent on you for those goods
since prices are too low to develop their own industries. I guess that’s their
problem though, right? Thanks to the empire, between 1870 and 1914 one half of
English savings were invested abroad and the interest from foreign investments
was one tenth of national income.
Then the
book has a chapter on Thorstein Veblen, who made a lot of sociological and
anthropological observations about the economy. For example, some goods people
want to buy because of their high price, not their low price, as they advertise
a certain level of wealth. He connected this back to earlier human times, when “savage”
humans would admire the war-like members of their society who tool what they
wanted. He argued that the same happened in the modern day. Instead of rising
up, he thought the proletariat would rather become like the bourgeoisie and emulate
them. He argued that capitalists were not the drivers of the economic machine
but its saboteurs, seeking to sneak away with the profits from it, weakening
the economic “machine.”
The last
two chapters of the book are fantastic and the penultimate is about John Maynard
Keynes. He made his name criticizing the Treaty of Versailles that ended World
War One and became even more famous for arguing for government intervention to
end the Great Depression. It had been thought that any recession or recession would
right itself as it would be caused by too much saving and eventually those
savings would get spent. However, Keynes realized that when it was bad enough
there would be no savings left for the vast majority of people to spend and pump
back into the economy. Therefore, he advocated for “priming the pump,” that the
government would start the spending and then people would find work, earning
more money to spend, restarting the economy. The trouble was not turning the “faucet
of spending” on, but rather turning it off to manage the inflation that would come
afterwards. He wanted governments to manage the economy but today it remains
unclear if that is possible.
The final
chapter discusses the Austrian economist Joseph Schumpeter, another one of the
best chapters of the book. He argued that an economy in equilibrium was not the
end state, but rather he conceived of it as the start. He imagined everything
circulating and being traded without any profits. Like a river, the economy
would find the path of least resistance and become more and more efficient
until there were not profits, which were inefficiencies in the system of trade.
However, profits could be created by the introduction of an obstacle in the
river’s path, a new invention or innovation. Therefore, the source of profits
in an economy was not the capitalist nor was it the worker but the inventor. Calling
these people entrepreneurs, Schumpeter
argued that they introduced true advances into the economy but rarely benefitted
greatly as everyone starts to copy them quickly, gradually reducing the profits
to be gained and returning the economy to an equilibrium until another
innovation would come about. Schumpeter predicted that in the long term, capitalism
would not last due not to economic reasons but sociological reasons. He thought
it was not that the proletarians would rise up however, but because innovation
would become institutionalized and bureaucratized, with the system becoming
almost too rational until it dies, lacking those romantic entrepreneurs.
To end,
Heilbroner writes three changes brought about by capitalism. The first is that
it legitimated the gain of wealth not just by Kings but by everyone who can
manage to do it in society. Next, it allowed “the encouragements and
discouragements of the market” to determine what should be produced rather than
being commanded by a man or woman. And last, it is the “first society to place
its overall guidance under two authorities, one public, one private, each with
its own powers and its boundaries to power. In sum, great introduction to
economic thought. I am a big fan and would recommend it to newcomers to
economics who have taken a few classes but want to know more like I did.
Miscellaneous Facts:
- With the share Queen Elizabeth received as a stockholder in Sir Francis Drake’s voyage of the Golden Hynd, she paid off all of England’s foreign debts, balanced the budget, and invested abroad enough at compound interest to account for all of Britain’s overseas wealth in 1930. Wow.
- In 1813, wheat was selling one bushel for twice the wages of a workingman in a week in England. I may have underestimated Napoleon’s continental system when I read it last.
No comments:
Post a Comment